Neoliberalismus



 

 

to accept reality is to submit to the overall order of the market

and its system of rewards and sanctions.

 

Friedrich Hayek

 

 


 

 

Was ist Neoliberalismus?

 

Ein Crashkurs zu den Unterschieden zum politischen Liberalismus sowie den Hauptakteuren, Auswirkungen und Alternativen.

 

Christian Felber, Freitag, 16. August 2013 - diesseits.de - Das Humanistische Magazin

 

Neoliberalismus ist im Grunde eine „reinere“ Form des Kapitalismus oder der kapitalistischen Marktwirtschaft, nachdem diese unter dem Eindruck der Weltwirtschaftskrise und des darauf folgenden 2. Weltkrieges einige Jahrzehnte lang sozial „abgefedert“ wurde, in Europa in Gestalt der „sozialen Marktwirtschaft“ und in den USA in Form des „New Deal“.

 

 Mit dem politischen Liberalismus hat Neoliberalismus wenig am Hut, in einem entscheidenden Aspekt können sie sogar als Gegenteile betrachtet werden. Der politische Liberalismus steht für den Vorrang politischer Freiheiten und der Grundrechte vor den reinen Wirtschaftsfreiheiten. Der Neoliberalismus kehrt dieses Verhältnis um: Die Wirtschaftsfreiheiten erhalten Vorrang vor allem anderen: „Geht’s der Wirtschaft gut, geht’s allen gut.“

 

Während im politischen Liberalismus der Staat den Markt einrichtet und reguliert, soll im Neoliberalismus der Markt die gesamte Gesellschaft regulieren und formen. Nicht liberté, egalité und fraternité sind die Grundsätze des Neoliberalismus, sondern Konkurrenz und Besitzfreiheit. Der große Buhmann des Neoliberalismus ist der Staat: Er würde dem Markt nur unnötig dreinpfuschen und solle sich „aus der Wirtschaft zurückziehen“: weniger Staat, mehr

privat!

 

Liberalisierung, Deregulierung, Privatisierung – das ist die Politik des Neoliberalismus: Freier Kapitalverkehr, Freihandel, freies globales Investieren, Freiheit von demokratischer Regulierung. Auf das Individuum gemünzt soll sich jede und jeder nur noch um sich selbst kümmern: „Eigenverantwortung!“ Gesamtgesellschaftliche und demokratische Verantwortung sind keine Tugenden im Neoliberalismus, allenfalls sollen die Menschen als KonsumentInnen

und AnlegerInnen Verantwortung ausüben („kritischer Konsum“, „ethische Geldanlage“).

 

Margaret Thatchers erhob Vereinzelung zum Programm: „There is no such thing as society.“ Es gibt keine Gesellschaft, nur isolierte Schluckspechte und EllenbogenkämpferInnen. Wie ist die Entstehungsgeschichte? Als Vordenker des Neoliberalismus gilt der österreichische Ökonom Friedrich August von Hayek, der 1947 die „Mont-Pelerin-Society“ (MPS) gründete, um neoliberales Gedankengut weltweit zu verbreiten. Dieses Netzwerk schaffte es, dass 1968 der „Preis für

Wirtschaftswissenschaften der Schwedischen Reichsbank in Gedenken an Alfred Nobel“ ins Leben gerufen wurde, welcher seither fälschlicherweise als „Wirtschaftsnobelpreis“ bezeichnet und zeitgleich mit den Nobelpreisen verliehen wird. Nicht weniger als acht Mitglieder der MPS erhielten in kurzer Abfolge diesen Preis, darunter einige von Hayeks Schülern an der Universität von Chicago, die so genannten „Chicago Boys“. Der berühmteste „Boy“ war Milton Friedman, der in den 70er Jahren in der Diktatur von Augusto Pinochet neoliberale Experimente durchführen durfte und dafür als ökonomischer Popstar gefeiert wurde. In den 80er-Jahren setzten die USA („Reaganomics“) und Großbritannien („Thatcherism“) neoliberale Konzepte um. Seither breitet sich neoliberale Politik über den gesamten Erdball aus.

 

Welche Auswirkungen hat neoliberale Politik?

 

Steuerbegünstigungen für Reiche, Sozialabbau und Privatisierungen bewirken das Anwachsen von Ungleichheit und die Auflösung des sozialen Zusammenhalts. In den USA verdient heute der bestbezahlte Manager ein Jahreseinkommen von 3,7 Milliarden US-Dollar: das 290.000-fache des gesetzlichen Mindestlohnes. Dieser hat seit 1968 40 Prozent seiner Kaufkraft verloren. Mit der Armut steigt die Kriminalität in den USA sprunghaft an, die Zahl der Gefängnisinsassen

explodierte von 500.000 im Jahr 1980 auf über zwei Millionen heute. Für jeden achten farbigen jungen Mann endet der „American Dream“ hinter schwedischen Gardinen.

 

Die Macht der Reichen und Konzerne ist so groß geworden, dass sie erfolgreich die Demokratie instrumentalisiert haben. Die Politik trifft die wichtigsten Entscheidungen zugunsten einer Minderheit. Das hat wiederum die Abwendung vieler Menschen von der Politik („Politikverdrossenheit“) und weit verbreitete Ohnmachtgefühle zur Folge.

 

Wer sind relevante PlayerInnen?

 

Hauptakteure sind die Regierungen in fast allen Ländern, die in den letzten 20 Jahren zunehmend neoliberale Pro-gramme umgesetzt haben. Gleichzeitig nützen sie internationale Organisationen und suprastaatliche Strukturen, um unpopuläre Reformen („Schocks“) an den Parlamenten und Bevölkerungen vorbei durchzusetzen. Neben der „unhei-ligen Triade“ Weltbank, Währungsfonds (IWF) und Welthandelsorganisation (WTO) funktioniert insbesondere in der EU dieses „Spiel über die Bande“ gut: Was zu Hause nicht mehrheitsfähig ist, machen wir über Brüssel und stellen es als „Sachzwang“ (der Globalisierung) dar. Weitere Player sind die OECD, die regelmäßig über das „großzügige“ Pensions-system in Österreich meckert oder der Sachverständigenrat in Deutschland („Wirtschaftsweise“), in dessen Empfeh-lungen sich der Generalschwenk der Wirtschaftswissenschaft zum Neoliberalismus spiegelt. Schließlich finden sich zunehmend neoliberale Inhalte in den Programmen der großen Parteien: Vom „Sozialismus“ ist in den sozialdemo-kratischen Parteiprogrammen ebenso wenig übrig geblieben wie von der christlichen Soziallehre in der Politik der konservativen Parteien.

 

 In dem Maße, in dem die breite Bevölkerung neoliberale Phrasen und Glaubenssätze übernimmt („Leistungsträger müssen belohnt werden“, „Geht’s der Wirtschaft gut, geht’s uns allen gut“, „Wettbewerbsfähigkeit ist die Voraussetzung für unseren Wohlstand“), tragen wir alle zur „neoliberalen Hegemonie“ bei: Eine Mehrheit unterstützt, was einer Minderheit nützt. Derzeit ist der Neoliberalismus (noch) das herrschende „Paradigma“: ein Werte- und Argumentations-system, das die Hoheit im öffentlichen Diskurs besitzt. In dem Maße, in dem es die Wirklichkeit immer weniger erklären kann („Die Finanzmärkte regulieren sich am besten selbst“), wird es jedoch an Strahlkraft einbüßen und einem neuen Paradigma weichen.

 

Wer sind die KritikerInnen?

 

Der Streit um den wirtschaftswissenschaftlichen und wirtschaftspolitischen Hauptstrom ist in den letzten 250 Jahren von einem Tauziehen zwischen marktliberaleren Ansätzen (der ursprüngliche Liberalismus; die Zeit vor dem Wall-Street-Krach) und sozialeren Ansätzen (Marxismus, Kommunismus, soziale Marktwirtschaft, Globalisierungskritik) gekenn-zeichnet. Das Ahlener Programm der CDU Nordrhein-Westfalen von 1947, das zum christlichen Sozialismus schwenkte, wurde mit nur einer Stimme Mehrheit angenommen. Ähnlich graduell erfolgte der Übergang zum Neoliberalismus in den letzten 30 Jahren. Kritische ÖkonomInnen haben von Anfang an vor dieser Entwicklung gewarnt. Die linken Flügel der grünen und sozialdemokratischen Parteien und die Gewerkschaften kritisieren den Neoliberalismus ebenso

wie die christlich-soziale Basis der Konservativen. Auch in UnternehmerInnenkreisen, insbesondere bei regionalen Betrieben, wächst die Unzufriedenheit mit der aktuellen Entwicklung der Wirtschaft. Schließlich engagiert sich eine wachsende Zahl besorgter und betroffener Menschen in sozialen Bewegungen wie Attac, die sich seit 2001 im Weltsozialforum und in kontinentalen Foren treffen. Nobelpreisträger wie Joseph Stiglitz verleihen der globa-lisierungskritischen Bewegung Prominenz und Glaubwürdigkeit.

 

Welche Alternativen werden diskutiert?

 

 Die in Diskussion befindlichen Alternativen drehen sich vorwiegend um eine stärkere Rolle des Staates, der die Marktkräfte ausgleichen, steuern und stabilisieren soll. Menschenrechte, Verteilungsgerechtigkeit und Umweltschutz sollen Vorrang erhalten vor Wirtschaftsfreiheiten. Voraussetzung dieser geänderten Rolle des Staates – Politik für die Mehrheit – ist jedoch seine Demokratisierung. Die repräsentative Demokratie müsste korrigiert werden durch Elemente

partizipativer und direkter Demokratie sowie durch die Einhaltung des Subsidiaritätsprinzips bei der Europäischen Integration und der Bildung von Global-Governance-Strukturen („globale Regulierung ohne Weltregierung“). Radikalere Ansätze zielen auf die Überwindung der kapitalistischer Marktwirtschaft in Richtung „bedürfnisorientierter Versorgungs-wirtschaft“, „dezentraler Planwirtschaft“, Geschenkwirtschaft, Subsistenzwirtschaft oder allgemein „solidarischem Wirtschaften“, zum Teil ohne Geld und Staat. Die wichtigste Voraussetzung für tief greifende Veränderungen ist das Engagement jeder und jedes Einzelnen. Von alleine werden die Herrschenden keine Macht abgeben und die Parteien ihre Programme nicht umschreiben. Demokratie und sozialer Fortschritt haben ihren Preis.

 

 

***

 

 

Was ist Neoliberalismus?

 

 GASTKOMMENTAR - 18.11.2013

 

Ich stimme mit den Ausführungen gar nicht überein.

 

Der Begriff "Neoliberalismus" wurde 1938 von Alexander Rüstow geprägt. Rüstow forderte damit einen sozial verpflichteten Liberalismus. Das war ein bewußter Gegenentwurf zu einem alten Liberalismus, den er Paläoliberalismus nannte. Der Ökonom und Soziologe Rüstow war ein Sozialliberaler durch und durch.

 

Das was heute irrtümlich oder diffamierend "Neoliberalismus" genannt wird, bezeichnete man früher als Laissez-faire. Einer der Ökonomen, die heute als Neoliberale charakterisiert werden, war Walter Eucken. Sein Hauptwiderstand richtete sich gegen einen ungezügelten Kapitalismus, der zu Monopolen und Kartellen neigt. Er forderte deshalb immer einen starken Staat, der den Marktmechanismus gegen die wirtschaftlich mächtigen Akteure durchzusetzen fähig ist.

 

Sogar Friedrich August von Hayek hielt eine freiheitliche Wirtschafts- und Gesellschaftsordnung mit dem Sozialstaat für vereinbar. (Der Weg zur Knechtschaft, München 1970, S. 60)

 

Ökonomen, die man nach heutigem Verständnis als neoliberal, oder besser gesagt als Anhänger von Laissez-faire, bezeichnen könnte, sind z. B. Ludwig von Mises oder Milton Friedman. Dass die Wirtschaftsliberalen Ende der 70er Jahre verstärktes Interesse erfuhren lag am Scheitern der Keynes´schen Globalsteuerungspolitik. Aber auch hier gibt es ein Mißverständnis. Hier handelt es sich nämlich um die Frage nach der besseren Kunjunkturpolitik und nicht der Ordnungspolitik.

 

Was ist Neoliberalismus? http://www.diesseits.de/print/schwerpunkt/bundestagswahl-2013/1376...

 

Sebastian Müller, Der Anbruch des Neoliberalismus

 

https://mediashop.at/buecher/der-anbruch-des-neoliberalismus/

 


 

 

Neoliberalism – the ideology at the root of all our problems

 

George Monbiot, The Guardian, April 15, 2016

 

Financial meltdown, environmental disaster and even the rise of Donald Trump – neoliberalism has played its part in them all. Why has the left failed to come up with an alternative?

 

Imagine if the people of the Soviet Union had never heard of communism. The ideology that dominates our lives has, for most of us, no name. Mention it in conversation and you’ll be rewarded with a shrug. Even if your listeners have heard the term before, they will struggle to define it. Neoliberalism: do you know what it is?

 

Its anonymity is both a symptom and cause of its power. It has played a major role in a remarkable variety of crises: the financial meltdown of 2007 8, the offshoring of wealth and power, of which the Panama Papers offer us merely a glimpse, the slow collapse of public health and education, resurgent child poverty, the epidemic of loneliness, the collapse of ecosystems, the rise of Donald Trump. But we respond to these crises as if they emerge in isolation, apparently unaware that they have all been either catalysed or exacerbated by the same coherent philosophy; a philosophy that has – or had – a name. What greater power can there be than to operate namelessly?

 

So pervasive has neoliberalism become that we seldom even recognise it as an ideology. We appear to accept the proposition that this utopian, millenarian faith describes a neutral force; a kind of biological law, like Darwin’s theory of evolution. But the philosophy arose as a conscious attempt to reshape human life and shift the locus of power.

 

Neoliberalism sees competition as the defining characteristic of human relations. It redefines citizens as consumers, whose democratic choices are best exercised by buying and selling, a process that rewards merit and punishes inefficiency. It maintains that “the market” delivers benefits that could never be achieved by planning.

 

Attempts to limit competition are treated as inimical to liberty. Tax and regulation should be minimised, public services should be privatised. The organisation of labour and collective bargaining by are portrayed as market distortions that impede the formation of a natural hierarchy of winners and losers. Inequality is recast as virtuous: a reward for utility and a generator of wealth, which trickles down to enrich everyone. Efforts to create a more equal society are both counterproductive and morally corrosive. The market ensures that everyone gets what they deserve.

 

We internalise and reproduce its creeds. The rich persuade themselves that they acquired their wealth through merit, ignoring the advantages – such as education, inheritance and class – that may have helped to secure it. The poor begin to blame themselves for their failures, even when they can do little to change their circumstances.

 

Never mind structural unemployment: if you don’t have a job it’s because you are unenterprising. Never mind the impossible costs of housing: if your credit card is maxed out, you’re feckless and improvident. Never mind that your children no longer have a school playing field: if they get fat, it’s your fault. In a world governed by competition, those who fall behind become defined and self-defined as losers.

 

Among the results, as Paul Verhaeghe documents in his book What About Me? are epidemics of self-harm, eating disorders, depression, loneliness, performance anxiety and social phobia. Perhaps it’s unsurprising that Britain, in which neoliberal ideology has been most rigorously applied, is the loneliness capital of Europe. We are all neoliberals now.

 

The term neoliberalism was coined at a meeting in Paris in 1938. Among the delegates were two men who came to define the ideology, Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich Hayek. Both exiles from Austria, they saw social democracy, exemplified by Franklin Roosevelt’s New Deal and the gradual development of Britain’s welfare state, as manifestations of a collectivism that occupied the same spectrum as nazism and communism.

 

In The Road to Serfdom, published in 1944, Hayek argued that government planning, by crushing individualism, would lead inexorably to totalitarian control. Like Mises’s book Bureaucracy, The Road to Serfdom was widely read. It came to the attention of some very wealthy people, who saw in the philosophy an opportunity to free themselves from regulation and tax. When, in 1947, Hayek founded the first organisation that would spread the doctrine of neoliberalism – the Mont Pelerin Society – it was supported financially by millionaires and their foundations.

 

With their help, he began to create what Daniel Stedman Jones describes in Masters of the Universe as “a kind of neoliberal international”: a transatlantic network of academics, businessmen, journalists and activists. The movement’s rich backers funded a series of thinktanks which would refine and promote the ideology. Among them were the American Enterprise Institute, the Heritage Foundation, the Cato Institute, the Institute of Economic Affairs, the Centre for Policy Studies and the Adam Smith Institute. They also financed academic positions and departments, particularly at the universities of Chicago and Virginia.

 

As it evolved, neoliberalism became more strident. Hayek’s view that governments should regulate competition to prevent monopolies from forming gave way – among American apostles such as Milton Friedman – to the belief that monopoly power could be seen as a reward for efficiency.

 

Something else happened during this transition: the movement lost its name. In 1951, Friedman was happy to describe himself as a neoliberal. But soon after that, the term began to disappear. Stranger still, even as the ideology became crisper and the movement more coherent, the lost name was not replaced by any common alternative.

 

At first, despite its lavish funding, neoliberalism remained at the margins. The postwar consensus was almost universal: John Maynard Keynes’s economic prescriptions were widely applied, full employment and the relief of poverty were common goals in the US and much of western Europe, top rates of tax were high and governments sought social outcomes without embarrassment, developing new public services and safety nets.

 

But in the 1970s, when Keynesian policies began to fall apart and economic crises struck on both sides of the Atlantic, neoliberal ideas began to enter the mainstream. As Friedman remarked, “when the time came that you had to change ... there was an alternative ready there to be picked up”. With the help of sympathetic journalists and political advisers, elements of neoliberalism, especially its prescriptions for monetary policy, were adopted by Jimmy Carter’s administration in the US and Jim Callaghan’s government in Britain.

 

After Margaret Thatcher and Ronald Reagan took power, the rest of the package soon followed: massive tax cuts for the rich, the crushing of trade unions, deregulation, privatisation, outsourcing and competition in public services. Through the IMF, the World Bank, the Maastricht treaty and the World Trade Organisation, neoliberal policies were imposed – often without democratic consent – on much of the world. Most remarkable was its adoption among parties that once belonged to the left: Labour and the Democrats, for example. As Stedman Jones notes, “it is hard to think of another utopia to have been as fully realised.”

 

It may seem strange that a doctrine promising choice and freedom should have been promoted with the slogan “there is no alternative”. But, as Hayek remarked on a visit to Pinochet’s Chile – one of the first nations in which the programme was comprehensively applied – “my personal preference leans toward a liberal dictatorship rather than toward a democratic government devoid of liberalism”. The freedom that neoliberalism offers, which sounds so beguiling when expressed in general terms, turns out to mean freedom for the pike, not for the minnows.

 

Freedom from trade unions and collective bargaining means the freedom to suppress wages. Freedom from regulation means the freedom to poison rivers, endanger workers, charge iniquitous rates of interest and design exotic financial instruments. Freedom from tax means freedom from the distribution of wealth that lifts people out of poverty.

 

As Naomi Klein documents in The Shock Doctrine, neoliberal theorists advocated the use of crises to impose unpopular policies while people were distracted: for example, in the aftermath of Pinochet’s coup, the Iraq war and Hurricane Katrina, which Friedman described as “an opportunity to radically reform the educational system” in New Orleans.

 

Where neoliberal policies cannot be imposed domestically, they are imposed internationally, through trade treaties incorporating “investor-state dispute settlement”: offshore tribunals in which corporations can press for the removal of social and environmental protections. When parliaments have voted to restrict sales of cigarettes, protect water supplies from mining companies, freeze energy bills or prevent pharmaceutical firms from ripping off the state, corporations have sued, often successfully. Democracy is reduced to theatre.

 

Another paradox of neoliberalism is that universal competition relies upon universal quantification and comparison. The result is that workers, job-seekers and public services of every kind are subject to a pettifogging, stifling regime of assessment and monitoring, designed to identify the winners and punish the losers. The doctrine that Von Mises proposed would free us from the bureaucratic nightmare of central planning has instead created one.

 

Neoliberalism was not conceived as a self-serving racket, but it rapidly became one. Economic growth has been markedly slower in the neoliberal era (since 1980 in Britain and the US) than it was in the preceding decades; but not for the very rich. Inequality in the distribution of both income and wealth, after 60 years of decline, rose rapidly in this era, due to the smashing of trade unions, tax reductions, rising rents, privatisation and deregulation.

 

The privatisation or marketisation of public services such as energy, water, trains, health, education, roads and prisons has enabled corporations to set up tollbooths in front of essential assets and charge rent, either to citizens or to government, for their use. Rent is another term for unearned income. When you pay an inflated price for a train ticket, only part of the fare compensates the operators for the money they spend on fuel, wages, rolling stock and other outlays. The rest reflects the fact that they have you over a barrel.

 

Those who own and run the UK’s privatised or semi-privatised services make stupendous fortunes by investing little and charging much. In Russia and India, oligarchs acquired state assets through firesales. In Mexico, Carlos Slim was granted control of almost all landline and mobile phone services and soon became the world’s richest man.

 

Financialisation, as Andrew Sayer notes in Why We Can’t Afford the Rich, has had a similar impact. “Like rent,” he argues, “interest is ... unearned income that accrues without any effort”. As the poor become poorer and the rich become richer, the rich acquire increasing control over another crucial asset: money. Interest payments, overwhelmingly, are a transfer of money from the poor to the rich. As property prices and the withdrawal of state funding load people with debt (think of the switch from student grants to student loans), the banks and their executives clean up.

 

Sayer argues that the past four decades have been characterised by a transfer of wealth not only from the poor to the rich, but within the ranks of the wealthy: from those who make their money by producing new goods or services to those who make their money by controlling existing assets and harvesting rent, interest or capital gains. Earned income has been supplanted by unearned income.

 

Neoliberal policies are everywhere beset by market failures. Not only are the banks too big to fail, but so are the corporations now charged with delivering public services. As Tony Judt pointed out in Ill Fares the Land, Hayek forgot that vital national services cannot be allowed to collapse, which means that competition cannot run its course. Business takes the profits, the state keeps the risk.

 

The greater the failure, the more extreme the ideology becomes. Governments use neoliberal crises as both excuse and opportunity to cut taxes, privatise remaining public services, rip holes in the social safety net, deregulate corporations and re-regulate citizens. The self-hating state now sinks its teeth into every organ of the public sector.

 

Perhaps the most dangerous impact of neoliberalism is not the economic crises it has caused, but the political crisis. As the domain of the state is reduced, our ability to change the course of our lives through voting also contracts. Instead, neoliberal theory asserts, people can exercise choice through spending. But some have more to spend than others: in the great consumer or shareholder democracy, votes are not equally distributed. The result is a disempowerment of the poor and middle. As parties of the right and former left adopt similar neoliberal policies, disempowerment turns to disenfranchise-ment. Large numbers of people have been shed from politics.

 

Chris Hedges remarks that “fascist movements build their base not from the politically active but the politically inactive, the ‘losers’ who feel, often correctly, they have no voice or role to play in the political establishment”. When political debate no longer speaks to us, people become responsive instead to slogans, symbols and sensation. To the admirers of Trump, for example, facts and arguments appear irrelevant.

 

Judt explained that when the thick mesh of interactions between people and the state has been reduced to nothing but authority and obedience, the only remaining force that binds us is state power. The totalitarianism Hayek feared is more likely to emerge when governments, having lost the moral authority that arises from the delivery of public services, are reduced to “cajoling, threatening and ultimately coercing people to obey them”.

 

Like communism, neoliberalism is the God that failed. But the zombie doctrine staggers on, and one of the reasons is its anonymity. Or rather, a cluster of anonymities.

 

The invisible doctrine of the invisible hand is promoted by invisible backers. Slowly, very slowly, we have begun to discover the names of a few of them. We find that the Institute of Economic Affairs, which has argued forcefully in the media against the further regulation of the tobacco industry, has been secretly funded by British American Tobacco since 1963. We discover that Charles and David Koch, two of the richest men in the world, founded the institute that set up the Tea Party movement. We find that Charles Koch, in establishing one of his thinktanks, noted that “in order to avoid undesirable criticism, how the organisation is controlled and directed should not be widely advertised”.

 

The words used by neoliberalism often conceal more than they elucidate. “The market” sounds like a natural system that might bear upon us equally, like gravity or atmospheric pressure. But it is fraught with power relations. What “the market wants” tends to mean what corporations and their bosses want. “Investment”, as Sayer notes, means two quite different things. One is the funding of productive and socially useful activities, the other is the purchase of existing assets to milk them for rent, interest, dividends and capital gains. Using the same word for different activities “camouflages the sources of wealth”, leading us to confuse wealth extraction with wealth creation.

 

A century ago, the nouveau riche were disparaged by those who had inherited their money. Entrepreneurs sought social acceptance by passing themselves off as rentiers. Today, the relationship has been reversed: the rentiers and inheritors style themselves entrepreneurs. They claim to have earned their unearned income.

 

These anonymities and confusions mesh with the namelessness and placelessness of modern capitalism: the franchise model which ensures that workers do not know for whom they toil; the companies registered through a network of offshore secrecy regimes so complex that even the police cannot discover the beneficial owners; the tax arrangements that bamboozle governments; the financial products no one understands.

 

The anonymity of neoliberalism is fiercely guarded. Those who are influenced by Hayek, Mises and Friedman tend to reject the term, maintaining – with some justice – that it is used today only pejoratively. But they offer us no substitute. Some describe themselves as classical liberals or libertarians, but these descriptions are both misleading and curiously self-effacing, as they suggest that there is nothing novel about The Road to Serfdom, Bureaucracy or Friedman’s classic work, Capitalism and Freedom.

 

For all that, there is something admirable about the neoliberal project, at least in its early stages. It was a distinctive, innovative philosophy promoted by a coherent network of thinkers and activists with a clear plan of action. It was patient and persistent. The Road to Serfdom became the path to power.

 

Neoliberalism’s triumph also reflects the failure of the left. When laissez-faire economics led to catastrophe in 1929, Keynes devised a comprehensive economic theory to replace it. When Keynesian demand management hit the buffers in the 70s, there was an alternative ready. But when neoliberalism fell apart in 2008 there was ... nothing. This is why the zombie walks. The left and centre have produced no new general framework of economic thought for 80 years.

 

Every invocation of Lord Keynes is an admission of failure. To propose Keynesian solutions to the crises of the 21st century is to ignore three obvious problems. It is hard to mobilise people around old ideas; the flaws exposed in the 70s have not gone away; and, most importantly, they have nothing to say about our gravest predicament: the environmental crisis. Keynesianism works by stimulating consumer demand to promote economic growth. Consumer demand and economic growth are the motors of environmental destruction.

 

What the history of both Keynesianism and neoliberalism show is that it’s not enough to oppose a broken system. A coherent alternative has to be proposed. For Labour, the Democrats and the wider left, the central task should be to develop an economic Apollo programme, a conscious attempt to design a new system, tailored to the demands of the 21st century.

 

George Monbiot’s How Did We Get into This Mess? is published this month by Verso.

 

To order a copy for £12.99 (RRP £16.99) ) go to bookshop.theguardian.com or call 0330 333 6846. Free UK p&p over £10, online orders only. Phone orders min p&p of £1.99

 

 https://www.theguardian.com/books/2016/apr/15/neoliberalism-ideology-problem-george-monbiot